Price

From Evolution and Games

(Difference between revisions)
Jump to: navigation, search
(Introduction)
(Extra links)
 
(6 intermediate revisions not shown)
Line 6: Line 6:
The Price equation zooms in on transitions from one generation to the next. This suggests that it could be a fundamental tool for understanding this
The Price equation zooms in on transitions from one generation to the next. This suggests that it could be a fundamental tool for understanding this
-
process of evolution. It was formulated by George Richard Price in 1970 [http://www.nature.com/nature/journal/v227/n5257/abs/227520a0.html in an article in Nature], and acclaimed by some, maybe even quite a few, to be a fundamental ingredient for models of evolution ([http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2008.01.005 Gardner], [http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jtbi.1995.0148 Frank], [http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jtbi.2002.3015 Grafen]). We think not. The reason why it is hard to identify it as such is that it is all about probability theory and statistics, and those two topics are just not that easy. The following tutorial will help by looking at what proper probability theory or statistics would do and compare that to what the Price equation does to numbers that represent those transitions. There is [http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jtbi.2005.04.026 an article with the same message], but this tutorial makes it simpler, by allowing you to play around with models, data and samples yourself. At some points you may find that the steps the tutorial takes are evident and all too easy, but it is possible that after a few steps, as simple as they are, you may nonetheless feel confused enough to make you want to retrace your steps and be happy, the second time around, that they are that simple. Or not, in which case you will just have an easy journey to a deep understanding why the Price equation is not what some say it is.
+
process of evolution. It was formulated by George Richard Price in 1970 [http://www.nature.com/nature/journal/v227/n5257/abs/227520a0.html in an article in Nature], and acclaimed by some, maybe even quite a few, to be a fundamental ingredient for models of evolution ([http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2008.01.005 Gardner], [http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jtbi.1995.0148 Frank], [http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jtbi.2002.3015 Grafen]). We think not. The reason why it is hard to identify it as such is that it is all about probability theory and statistics, and those two topics are just not that easy. The following tutorial will help by looking at what proper probability theory or statistics would do and compare that to what the Price equation does to numbers that represent those transitions. There is [http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jtbi.2005.04.026 an article with the same message], but this tutorial makes it simpler, by allowing you to play around with models, data and samples yourself. At some points you may find that the steps the tutorial takes are evident and all too easy, but it is possible that after a few steps, as simple as they are, you may nonetheless feel confused enough to make you want to retrace your steps and be happy, the second time around, that they are that simple. If this is not the case you will just have an easy journey to a deep understanding of why the Price equation is not what some say it is.
==Price 1.0: A very simple model ==
==Price 1.0: A very simple model ==
We will begin with the simplest real model that we can think of. No sex, no shrinking or expanding populations, no frequency dependence, no
We will begin with the simplest real model that we can think of. No sex, no shrinking or expanding populations, no frequency dependence, no
complications whatsoever. Just two individuals that are ready to reproduce. Asexually. This gives us a version of the Price equation that is even
complications whatsoever. Just two individuals that are ready to reproduce. Asexually. This gives us a version of the Price equation that is even
-
simpler than the first version by Price himself. And it will give us probability theory and statistics that is relatively nice and easy too, and therefore an excellent start that helps us get acquainted to the joys of rigour and precision.
+
simpler than the first version by Price himself. And it will give us probability theory and statistics that is relatively nice and easy too, and therefore an excellent start.
[[Price 1.0 | Go to the Tutorial ]]
[[Price 1.0 | Go to the Tutorial ]]
Line 28: Line 28:
== Price 3.0: A model with frequency dependence ==
== Price 3.0: A model with frequency dependence ==
-
We go back to the asexual model, but now we will take a model with frequency dependence. This will be a bit more complicated, but we can still use a basic, well known model. They are paired randomly, and play a game in those pairs. The game gives them payoffs according to a payoff matrix
+
We go back to the asexual model, but now we will take a model with frequency dependence. This will be a bit more complicated, but we can still use a basic, well known model. Individuals are randomly paired to play a game. The game gives them payoffs according to a payoff matrix
[[Price 3.0 | Go to the Tutorial ]]
[[Price 3.0 | Go to the Tutorial ]]
[[Price 3.0 Applet | Go straight to the software]]
[[Price 3.0 Applet | Go straight to the software]]
 +
 +
== Extra links ==
 +
* Please check the paper '''Group selection and inclusive fitness are not equivalent; the Price equation vs. models and statistics'''. van Veelen, Garcia, Egas, Sabellis. In press.  It is about the use of the price equation and the theory of inclusive fitness.  [http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0022519311003754 Link]
 +
 +
* John Maynard Smith [http://www.webofstories.com/play/7297 talks about the Price equation] and how this approach always felt unnatural to him. Since some of us remember a feeling of doubt when first confronted with the Price equation, it may be a relief to hear him say 'I'm not going to tell you what Price's theorem is, because I don't actually understand it'.

Current revision as of 08:30, 20 October 2011


Contents

Introduction

Evolution is all about transitions. One generation gives birth to the next, which gives birth to yet another generation, in an endless chain of transitions. These transitions don't just go anywhere; some transitions are more likely than others. First of all we beget offspring that is likely to bear some similarity with ourselves. And how likely we are to get offspring at all, and how many, tends to depend on certain heritable characteristics. The relative likelihood of some transitions and the relative improbability of others imply that we can make informed guesses as to where this endless chain of transitions came from and where it is going.

The Price equation zooms in on transitions from one generation to the next. This suggests that it could be a fundamental tool for understanding this process of evolution. It was formulated by George Richard Price in 1970 in an article in Nature, and acclaimed by some, maybe even quite a few, to be a fundamental ingredient for models of evolution (Gardner, Frank, Grafen). We think not. The reason why it is hard to identify it as such is that it is all about probability theory and statistics, and those two topics are just not that easy. The following tutorial will help by looking at what proper probability theory or statistics would do and compare that to what the Price equation does to numbers that represent those transitions. There is an article with the same message, but this tutorial makes it simpler, by allowing you to play around with models, data and samples yourself. At some points you may find that the steps the tutorial takes are evident and all too easy, but it is possible that after a few steps, as simple as they are, you may nonetheless feel confused enough to make you want to retrace your steps and be happy, the second time around, that they are that simple. If this is not the case you will just have an easy journey to a deep understanding of why the Price equation is not what some say it is.

Price 1.0: A very simple model

We will begin with the simplest real model that we can think of. No sex, no shrinking or expanding populations, no frequency dependence, no complications whatsoever. Just two individuals that are ready to reproduce. Asexually. This gives us a version of the Price equation that is even simpler than the first version by Price himself. And it will give us probability theory and statistics that is relatively nice and easy too, and therefore an excellent start.

Go to the Tutorial

Go straight to the software

Price 2.0: A model with sexual reproduction

If we add sexual reproduction, everything gets slightly more complicated, the proper statistics as well as the Price equation. This makes the statistics much more fun, and it makes the failure of the Price equation to be of any help even more salient. We like to keep it relatively simple though, so for the moment we do not assume actual different sexes, but we do assume that every individual is diploid.

Go to the Tutorial

Go straight to the software

Price 3.0: A model with frequency dependence

We go back to the asexual model, but now we will take a model with frequency dependence. This will be a bit more complicated, but we can still use a basic, well known model. Individuals are randomly paired to play a game. The game gives them payoffs according to a payoff matrix

Go to the Tutorial

Go straight to the software

Extra links

  • Please check the paper Group selection and inclusive fitness are not equivalent; the Price equation vs. models and statistics. van Veelen, Garcia, Egas, Sabellis. In press. It is about the use of the price equation and the theory of inclusive fitness. Link
  • John Maynard Smith talks about the Price equation and how this approach always felt unnatural to him. Since some of us remember a feeling of doubt when first confronted with the Price equation, it may be a relief to hear him say 'I'm not going to tell you what Price's theorem is, because I don't actually understand it'.